home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- Subject: 89-1671 -- OPINION, COLUMBIA v. OMNI OUTDOOR ADVERTISING, INC.
-
- NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in
- the preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested
- to notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States,
- Washington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in
- order that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to
- press.
- SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
-
-
- No. 89-1671
-
-
-
- CITY OF COLUMBIA and COLUMBIA OUTDOOR ADVERTISING, INC., PETITIONERS v.
- OMNI OUTDOOR ADVERTISING, INC.
-
- on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the fourth
- circuit
-
- [April 1, 1991]
-
-
-
- Justice Scalia delivered the opinion of the Court.
- This case requires us to clarify the application of the Sherman Act to
- municipal governments and to the citizens who seek action from them.
-
- I
- Petitioner Columbia Outdoor Advertising, Inc. (COA), a South Carolina
- corporation, entered the billboard business in the city of Columbia, South
- Carolina (also a petitioner here), in the 1940's. By 1981 it controlled
- more than 95% of what has been conceded to be the relevant market. COA was
- a local business owned by a family with deep roots in the community, and
- enjoyed close relations with the city's political leaders. The mayor and
- other members of the city council were personal friends of COA's majority
- owner, and the company and its officers occasionally contributed funds and
- free billboard space to their campaigns. According to respondent, these
- beneficences were part of a "longstanding" "secret anticompetitive
- agreement" whereby "the City and COA would each use their [sic] respective
- power and resources to protect . . . COA's monopoly position," in return
- for which "City Council members received advantages made possible by COA's
- monopoly." Brief for Respondent 12, 16.
- In 1981, respondent Omni Outdoor Advertising, Inc., a Georgia
- corporation, began erecting billboards in and around the city. COA
- responded to this competition in several ways. First, it redoubled its own
- billboard construction efforts and modernized its existing stock. Second
- -- according to Omni -- it took a number of anticompetitive private
- actions, such as offering artificially low rates, spreading untrue and
- malicious rumors about Omni, and attempting to induce Omni's customers to
- break their contracts. Finally (and this is what gives rise to the issue
- we address today), COA executives met with city officials to seek the
- enactment of zoning ordinances that would restrict billboard construction.
- COA was not alone in urging this course; a number of citizens concerned
- about the city's recent explosion of billboards advocated restrictions,
- including writers of articles and editorials in local newspapers.
- In the spring of 1982, the city council passed an ordinance requiring
- the council's approval for every billboard constructed in downtown
- Columbia. This was later amended to impose a 180-day moratorium on the
- construction of billboards throughout the city, except as specifically
- authorized by the council. A state court invalidated this ordinance on the
- ground that its conferral of unconstrained discretion upon the city council
- violated both the South Carolina and Federal Constitutions. The city then
- requested the State's regional planning authority to conduct a
- comprehensive analysis of the local billboard situation as a basis for
- developing a final, constitutionally valid, ordinance. In September 1982,
- after a series of public hearings and numerous meetings involving city
- officials, Omni, and COA (in all of which, according to Omni, positions
- contrary to COA's were not genuinely considered), the city council passed a
- new ordinance resticting the size, location, and spacing of billboards.
- These restrictions, particularly those on spacing, obviously benefited COA,
- which already had its billboards in place; they severely hindered Omni's
- ability to compete.
- In November 1982, Omni filed suit against COA and the city in Federal
- District Court, charging that they had violated 15 1 and 2 of the Sherman
- Act, 26 Stat. 209, as amended, 15 U. S. C. 15 1, 2, {1} as well as South
- Carolina's Unfair Trade Practices Act, S. C. Code MDRV 39-5-140 (1976).
- Omni contended, in particular, that the city's billboard ordinances were
- the result of an anticompetitive conspiracy between city officials and COA
- that stripped both parties of any immunity they might otherwise enjoy from
- the federal antitrust laws. In January 1986, after more than two weeks of
- trial, a jury returned general verdicts against the city and COA on both
- the federal and state claims. It awarded damages, before trebling, of
- $600,000 on the MDRV 1 Sherman Act claim, and $400,000 on the MDRV 2 claim.
- {2} The jury also answered two special interrogatories, finding
- specifically that the city and COA had conspired both to restrain trade and
- to monopolize the market. Petitioners moved for judgment notwithstanding
- the verdict, contending among other things that their activities were
- outside the scope of the federal antitrust laws. In November 1988, the
- District Court granted the motion.
- A divided panel of the United States Court of Appeals for the Fourth
- Circuit reversed the judgment of the District Court and reinstated the jury
- verdict on all counts. 891 F. 2d 1127 (1989). We granted certiorari, 496
- U. S. --- (1990).
-
- II
- In the landmark case of Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341 (1943), we
- rejected the contention that a program restricting the marketing of
- privately produced raisins, adopted pursuant to California's Agricultural
- Prorate Act, violated the Sherman Act. Relying on principles of federalism
- and state sovereignty, we held that the Sherman Act did not apply to
- anticompetitive restraints imposed by the States "as an act of government."
- 317 U. S., at 352.
- Since Parker emphasized the role of sovereign States in a federal
- system, it was initially unclear whether the governmental actions of
- political subdivisions enjoyed similar protection. In recent years, we
- have held that Parker immunity does not apply directly to local
- governments, see Hallie v. Eau Claire, 471 U. S. 34, 38 (1985); Community
- Communications Co. v. Boulder, 455 U. S. 40, 50-51 (1982); Lafayette v.
- Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U. S. 389, 412-413 (1978) (plurality
- opinion). We have recognized, however, that a municipality's restriction
- of competition may sometimes be an authorized implementation of state
- policy, and have accorded Parker immunity where that is the case. The
- South Carolina statutes under which the city acted in the present case
- authorize municipalities to regulate the use of land and the construction
- of buildings and other structures within their boundaries. {3} It is
- undisputed that, as a matter of state law, these statutes authorize the
- city to regulate the size, location, and spacing of billboards. It could
- be argued, however, that a municipality acts beyond its delegated
- authority, for Parker purposes, whenever the nature of its regulation is
- substantively or even procedurally defective. On such an analysis it could
- be contended, for example, that the city's regulation in the present case
- was not "authorized" by S. C. Code MDRV 5-23-10 (1976), see n. 3, supra, if
- it was not, as that statute requires, adopted "for the purpose of promoting
- health, safety, morals or the general welfare of the community." As
- scholarly commentary has noted, such an expansive interpretation of the
- Parker-defense authorization requirement would have unacceptable
- consequences.
-
- "To be sure, state law `authorizes' only agency decisions that are
- substantively and procedurally correct. Errors of fact, law, or judgment
- by the agency are not `authorized.' Erroneous acts or decisions are
- subject to reversal by superior tribunals because unauthorized. If the
- antitrust court demands unqualified `authority' in this sense, it
- inevitably becomes the standard reviewer not only of federal agency
- activity but also of state and local activity whenever it is alleged that
- the governmental body, though possessing the power to engage in the
- challenged conduct, has actually exercised its power in a manner not
- authorized by state law. We should not lightly assume that Lafayette's
- authorization requirement dictates transformation of state administrative
- review into a federal antitrust job. Yet that would be the consequence of
- making antitrust liability depend on an undiscriminating and mechanical
- demand for `authority' in the full administrative law sense." P. Areeda &
- H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law MDRV 212.3b, p. 145 (Supp. 1989).
-
-
- We agree with that assessment, and believe that in order to prevent Parker
- from undermining the very interests of federalism it is designed to
- protect, it is necessary to adopt a concept of authority broader than what
- is applied to determine the legality of the municipality's action under
- state law. We have adopted an approach that is similar in principle,
- though not necessarily in precise application, elsewhere. See Stump v.
- Sparkman, 435 U. S. 349 (1978). It suffices for the present to conclude
- that here no more is needed to establish, for Parker purposes, the city's
- authority to regulate than its unquestioned zoning power over the size,
- location, and spacing of billboards.
- Besides authority to regulate, however, the Parker defense also
- requires authority to suppress competition -- more specifically, "clear
- articulation of a state policy to authorize anticompetitive conduct" by the
- municipality in connection with its regulation. Hallie, 471 U. S., at 40
- (internal quotation omitted). We have rejected the contention that this
- requirement can be met only if the delegating statute explicitly permits
- the displacement of competition, see id., at 41-42. It is enough, we have
- held, if suppression of competition is the "foreseeable result" of what the
- statute authorizes, id., at 42. That condition is amply met here. The
- very purpose of zoning regulation is to displace unfettered business
- freedom in a manner that regularly has the effect of preventing normal acts
- of competition, particularly on the part of new entrants. A municipal
- ordinance restricting the size, location, and spacing of billboards (surely
- a common form of zoning) necessarily protects existing billboards against
- some competition from newcomers. {4}
- The Court of Appeals was therefore correct in its conclusion that the
- city's restriction of billboard construction was prima facie entitled to
- Parker immunity. The Court of Appeals upheld the jury verdict, however, by
- invoking a "conspiracy" exception to Parker that has been recognized by
- several Courts of Appeals. See, e. g., Whitworth v. Perkins, 559 F. 2d 378
- (CA5 1977), vacated, 435 U. S. 992, aff'd on rehearing, 576 F. 2d 696
- (1978), cert. denied, 440 U. S. 911 (1979). That exception is thought to
- be supported by two of our statements in Parker: "[W]e have no question of
- the state or its municipality becoming a participant in a private agreement
- or combination by others for restraint of trade, cf. Union Pacific R. Co.
- v. United States, 313 U. S. 450." Parker, 317 U. S., at 351-352 (emphasis
- added). "The state in adopting and enforcing the prorate program made no
- contract or agreement and entered into no conspiracy in restraint of trade
- or to establish monopoly but, as sovereign, imposed the restraint as an act
- of government which the Sherman Act did not undertake to prohibit." Id.,
- at 352 (emphasis added). Parker does not apply, according to the Fourth
- Circuit, "where politicians or political entities are involved as
- conspirators" with private actors in the restraint of trade. 891 F. 2d, at
- 1134.
- There is no such conspiracy exception. The rationale of Parker was
- that, in light of our national commitment to federalism, the general
- language of the Sherman Act should not be interpreted to prohibit
- anticompetitive actions by the States in their governmental capacities as
- sovereign regulators. The sentences from the opinion quoted above simply
- clarify that this immunity does not necessarily obtain where the State acts
- not in a regulatory capacity but as a commercial participant in a given
- market. That is evident from the citation of Union Pacific R. Co. v.
- United States, 313 U. S. 450 (1941), which held unlawful under the Elkins
- Act certain rebates and concessions made by Kansas City, Kansas, in its
- capacity as the owner and operator of a wholesale produce market that was
- integrated with railroad facilities. These sentences should not be read to
- suggest the general proposition that even governmental regulatory action
- may be deemed private -- and therefore subject to antitrust liability --
- when it is taken pursuant to a conspiracy with private parties. The
- impracticality of such a principle is evident if, for purposes of the
- exception, "conspiracy" means nothing more than an agreement to impose the
- regulation in question. Since it is both inevitable and desirable that
- public officials often agree to do what one or another group of private
- citizens urges upon them, such an exception would virtually swallow up the
- Parker rule: All anticompetitive regulation would be vulnerable to a
- "conspiracy" charge. See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, MDRV 203.3b, at 34,
- and n. 1; Elhauge, The Scope of Antitrust Process, 104 Harv. L. Rev. 667,
- 704-705 (1991). {5}
- Omni suggests, however, that "conspiracy" might be limited to instances
- of governmental "corruption," defined variously as "abandonment of public
- responsibilities to private interests," Brief for Respondent 42, "corrupt
- or bad faith decisions," id., at 44, and "selfish or corrupt motives,"
- ibid. Ultimately, Omni asks us not to define "corruption" at all, but
- simply to leave that task to the jury: "[a]t bottom, however, it was within
- the jury's province to determine what constituted corruption of the
- governmental process in their community." Id., at 43. Omni's amicus
- eschews this emphasis on "corruption," instead urging us to define the
- conspiracy exception as encompassing any governmental act "not in the
- public interest." Brief for Associated Builders and Contractors, Inc. as
- Amicus Curiae 5.
- A conspiracy exception narrowed along such vague lines is similarly
- impractical. Few governmental actions are immune from the charge that they
- are "not in the public interest" or in some sense "corrupt." The
- California marketing scheme at issue in Parker itself, for example, can
- readily be viewed as the result of a "conspiracy" to put the "private"
- interest of the State's raisin growers above the "public" interest of the
- State's consumers. The fact is that virtually all regulation benefits some
- segments of the society and harms others; and that it is not universally
- considered contrary to the public good if the net economic loss to the
- losers exceeds the net economic gain to the winners. Parker was not
- written in ignorance of the reality that determination of "the public
- interest" in the manifold areas of government regulation entails not merely
- economic and mathematical analysis but value judgment, and it was not meant
- to shift that judgment from elected officials to judges and juries. If the
- city of Columbia's decision to regulate what one local newspaper called
- "billboard jungles," Columbia Record, May 21, 1982, p. 14-A, col. 1; App.
- in No. 88-1388 (CA4), p. 3743, is made subject to ex post facto judicial
- assessment of "the public interest," with personal liability of city
- officials a possible consequence, we will have gone far to "compromise the
- States' ability to regulate their domestic commerce," Southern Motor
- Carriers Rate Conference, Inc. v. United States, 471 U. S. 48, 56 (1985).
- The situation would not be better, but arguably even worse, if the courts
- were to apply a subjective test: not whether the action was in the public
- interest, but whether the officials involved thought it to be so. This
- would require the sort of deconstruction of the governmental process and
- probing of the official "intent" that we have consistently sought to avoid.
- {6} "[W]here the action complained of . . . was that of the State itself,
- the action is exempt from antitrust liability regardless of the State's
- motives in taking the action." Hoover v. Ronwin, 466 U. S. 558, 579-580
- (1984). See also Llewellyn v. Crothers, 765 F. 2d 769, 774 (CA9 1985)
- (Kennedy, J.).
- The foregoing approach to establishing a "conspiracy" exception at
- least seeks (however impractically) to draw the line of impermissible
- action in a manner relevant to the purposes of the Sherman Act and of
- Parker: prohibiting the restriction of competition for private gain but
- permitting the restriction of competition in the public interest. Another
- approach is possible, which has the virtue of practicality but the vice of
- being unrelated to those purposes. That is the approach which would
- consider Parker inapplicable only if, in connection with the governmental
- action in question, bribery or some other violation of state or federal law
- has been established. Such unlawful activity has no necessary relationship
- to whether the governmental action is in the public interest. A mayor is
- guilty of accepting a bribe even if he would and should have taken, in the
- public interest, the same action for which the bribe was paid. (That is
- frequently the defense asserted to a criminal bribery charge -- and though
- it is never valid in law, see, e. g., United States v. Jannotti, 673 F. 2d
- 578, 601 (CA3) (en banc), cert. denied, 457 U. S. 1106 (1982), it is often
- plausible in fact.) When, moreover, the regulatory body is not a single
- individual but a state legislature or city council, there is even less
- reason to believe that violation of the law (by bribing a minority of the
- decisionmakers) establishes that the regulation has no valid public
- purpose. Cf. Fletcher v. Peck, 6 Cranch 87, 130 (1810). To use unlawful
- political influence as the test of legality of state regulation undoubtedly
- vindicates (in a rather blunt way) principles of good government. But the
- statute we are construing is not directed to that end. Congress has passed
- other laws aimed at combatting corruption in state and local governments.
- See, e. g., 18 U. S. C. MDRV 1951 (Hobbs Act). "Insofar as [the Sherman
- Act] sets up a code of ethics at all, it is a code that condemns trade
- restraints, not political activity." Eastern Railroad Presidents
- Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U. S. 127, 140 (1961).
- For these reasons, we reaffirm our rejection of any interpretation of
- the Sherman Act that would allow plaintiffs to look behind the actions of
- state sovereigns to base their claims on "perceived conspiracies to
- restrain trade," Hoover, 466 U. S., at 580. We reiterate that, with the
- possible market participant exception, any action that qualifies as state
- action is "ipso facto . . . exempt from the operation of the antitrust
- laws," id., at 568. This does not mean, of course, that the States may
- exempt private action from the scope of the Sherman Act; we in no way
- qualify the well established principle that "a state does not give immunity
- to those who violate the Sherman Act by authorizing them to violate it, or
- by declaring that their action is lawful." Parker, 317 U. S., at 351
- (citing Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U. S. 197, 332,
- 344-347 (1904)). See also Schwegmann Brothers v. Calvert Distillers Corp.,
- 341 U. S. 384 (1951).
-
- III
- While Parker recognized the States' freedom to engage in
- anticompetitive regulation, it did not purport to immunize from antitrust
- liability the private parties who urge them to engage in anticompetitive
- regulation. However, it is obviously peculiar in a democracy, and perhaps
- in derogation of the constitutional right "to petition the Government for a
- redress of grievances," U. S. Const., Amdt. 1, to establish a category of
- lawful state action that citizens are not permitted to urge. Thus,
- beginning with Eastern Railroad Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor
- Freight, Inc., supra, we have developed a corollary to Parker: the federal
- antitrust laws also do not regulate the conduct of private individuals in
- seeking anticompetitive action from the government. This doctrine, like
- Parker, rests ultimately upon a recognition that the antitrust laws,
- "tailored as they are for the business world, are not at all appropriate
- for application in the political arena." Noerr, supra, at 141. That a
- private party's political motives are selfish is irrelevant: "Noerr shields
- from the Sherman Act a concerted effort to influence public officials
- regardless of intent or purpose." United Mine Workers of America v.
- Pennington, 381 U. S. 657, 670 (1965).
- Noerr recognized, however, what has come to be known as the "sham"
- exception to its rule: "There may be situations in which a publicity
- campaign, ostensibly directed toward influencing governmental action, is a
- mere sham to cover what is actually nothing more than an attempt to
- interfere directly with the business relationships of a competitor and the
- application of the Sherman Act would be justified." 365 U. S., at 144.
- The Court of Appeals concluded that the jury in this case could have found
- that COA's activities on behalf of the restrictive billboard ordinances
- fell within this exception. In our view that was error.
- The "sham" exception to Noerr encompasses situations in which persons
- use the governmental process -- as opposed to the outcome of that process
- -- as an anticompetitive weapon. A classic example is the filing of
- frivolous objections to the license application of a competitor, with no
- expectation of achieving denial of the license but simply in order to
- impose expense and delay. See California Motor Transport Co. v. Trucking
- Unlimited, 404 U. S. 508 (1972). A "sham" situation involves a defendant
- whose activities are "not genuinely aimed at procuring favorable government
- action" at all, Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc., 486 U. S.
- 492, 500, n. 4 (1988), not one "who `genuinely seeks to achieve his
- governmental result, but does so through improper means,' " id., at 508, n.
- 10 (quoting Sessions Tank Liners, Inc. v. Joor Mfg., Inc., 827 F. 2d 458,
- 465, n. 5 (CA9 1987)).
- Neither of the Court of Appeals' theories for application of the "sham"
- exception to the facts of the present case is sound. The court reasoned,
- first, that the jury could have concluded that COA's interaction with city
- officials "was `actually nothing more than an attempt to interfere directly
- with the business relations [sic] of a competitor.' " 891 F. 2d, at 1139
- (quoting Noerr, supra, at 144). This analysis relies upon language from
- Noerr, but ignores the import of the critical word "directly." Although
- COA indisputably set out to disrupt Omni's business relationships, it
- sought to do so not through the very process of lobbying, or of causing the
- city council to consider zoning measures, but rather through the ultimate
- product of that lobbying and consideration, viz., the zoning ordinances.
- The Court of Appeals' second theory was that the jury could have found
- "that COA's purposes were to delay Omni's entry into the market and even to
- deny it a meaningful access to the appropriate city administrative and
- legislative fora." 891 F. 2d, at 1139. But the purpose of delaying a
- competitor's entry into the market does not render lobbying activity a
- "sham," unless (as no evidence suggested was true here) the delay is sought
- to be achieved only by the lobbying process itself, and not by the
- governmental action that the lobbying seeks. "If Noerr teaches anything it
- is that an intent to restrain trade as a result of government action sought
- . . . does not foreclose protection." Sullivan, Developments in the Noerr
- Doctrine, 56 Antitrust L. J. 361, 362 (1987). As for "deny[ing] . . .
- meaningful access to the appropriate city administrative and legislative
- fora," that may render the manner of lobbying improper or even unlawful,
- but does not necessarily render it a "sham." We did hold in California
- Motor Transport, supra, that a conspiracy among private parties to
- monopolize trade by excluding a competitor from participation in the
- regulatory process did not enjoy Noerr protection. But California Motor
- Transport involved a context in which the conspirators' participation in
- the governmental process was itself claimed to be a "sham," employed as a
- means of imposing cost and delay. ("It is alleged that petitioners
- `instituted the proceedings and actions . . . with or without probable
- cause, and regardless of the merits of the cases.' " 404 U. S., at 512.)
- The holding of the case is limited to that situation. To extend it to a
- context in which the regulatory process is being invoked genuinely, and not
- in a "sham" fashion, would produce precisely that conversion of antitrust
- law into regulation of the political process that we have sought to avoid.
- Any lobbyist or applicant, in addition to getting himself heard, seeks by
- procedural and other means to get his opponent ignored. Policing the
- legitimate boundaries of such defensive strategies, when they are conducted
- in the context of a genuine attempt to influence governmental action, is
- not the role of the Sherman Act. In the present case, of course, any
- denial to Omni of "meaningful access to the appropriate city administrative
- and legislative fora" was achieved by COA in the course of an attempt to
- influence governmental action that, far from being a "sham," was if
- anything more in earnest than it should have been. If the denial was
- wrongful there may be other remedies, but as for the Sherman Act, the Noerr
- exemption applies.
- Omni urges that if, as we have concluded, the "sham" exception is
- inapplicable, we should use this case to recognize another exception to
- Noerr immunity -- a "conspiracy" exception, which would apply when
- government officials conspire with a private party to employ government
- action as a means of stifling competition. We have left open the
- possibility of such an exception, see, e. g., Allied Tube, supra, at 502,
- n. 7, as have a number of Courts of Appeals. See, e. g., Oberndorf v.
- Denver, 900 F. 2d 1434, 1440 (CA10 1990); First American Title Co. of South
- Dakota v. South Dakota Land Title Assn., 714 F. 2d 1439, 1446, n. 6 (CA8
- 1983), cert. denied, 464 U. S. 1042 (1984). At least one Court of Appeals
- has affirmed the existence of such an exception in dicta, see Duke & Co. v.
- Foerster, 521 F. 2d 1277, 1282 (CA3 1975), and the Fifth Circuit has
- adopted it as holding, see Affiliated Capital Corp. v. Houston, 735 F. 2d
- 1555, 1566-1568 (1984) (en banc).
- Giving full consideration to this matter for the first time, we
- conclude that a "conspiracy" exception to Noerr must be rejected. We need
- not describe our reasons at length, since they are largely the same as
- those set forth in Part II above for rejecting a "conspiracy" exception to
- Parker. As we have described, Parker and Noerr are complementary
- expressions of the principle that the antitrust laws regulate business, not
- politics; the former decision protects the States' acts of governing, and
- the latter the citizens' participation in government. Insofar as the
- identification of an immunitydestroying "conspiracy" is concerned, Parker
- and Noerr generally present two faces of the same coin. The
- Noerr-invalidating conspiracy alleged here is just the Parker-invalidating
- conspiracy viewed from the standpoint of the private-sector participants
- rather than the governmental participants. The same factors which, as we
- have described above, make it impracticable or beyond the purpose of the
- antitrust laws to identify and invalidate lawmaking that has been infected
- by selfishly motivated agreement with private interests likewise make it
- impracticable or beyond that scope to identify and invalidate lobbying that
- has produced selfishly motivated agreement with public officials. "It
- would be unlikely that any effort to influence legislative action could
- succeed unless one or more members of the legislative body became . . .
- `coconspirators' " in some sense with the private party urging such action,
- Metro Cable Co. v. CATV of Rockford, Inc., 516 F. 2d 220, 230 (CA7 1975).
- And if the invalidating "conspiracy" is limited to one that involves some
- element of unlawfulness (beyond mere anticompetitive motivation), the
- invalidation would have nothing to do with the policies of the antitrust
- laws. In Noerr itself, where the private party "deliberately deceived the
- public and public officials" in its successful lobbying campaign, we said
- that "deception, reprehensible as it is, can be of no consequence so far as
- the Sherman Act is concerned." 365 U. S., at 145.
-
- IV
- Under Parker and Noerr, therefore, both the city and COA are entitled
- to immunity from the federal antitrust laws for their activities relating
- to enactment of the ordinances. This determination does not entirely
- resolve the dispute before us, since other activities are at issue in the
- case with respect to COA. Omni asserts that COA engaged in private
- anticompetitive actions such as trade libel, the setting of artificially
- low rates, and inducement to breach of contract. Thus, although the jury's
- general verdict against COA cannot be permitted to stand (since it was
- based on instructions that erroneously permitted liability for seeking the
- ordinances, see Sunkist Growers, Inc. v. Winckler & Smith Citrus Products
- Co., 370 U. S. 19, 29-30 (1962)) if the evidence was sufficient to sustain
- a verdict on the basis of these other actions alone, and if this theory of
- liability has been properly preserved, Omni would be entitled to a new
- trial.
- There also remains to be considered the effect of our judgment upon
- Omni's claim against COA under the South Carolina Unfair Trade Practices
- Act. The District Court granted judgment notwithstanding the verdict on
- this claim as well as the Sherman Act claims; the Court of Appeals reversed
- on the ground that "a finding of conspiracy to restrain competition is
- tantamount to a finding" that the South Carolina law had been violated, 891
- F. 2d, at 1143. Given our reversal of the "conspiracy" holding, that
- reasoning is no longer applicable.
- We leave these remaining questions for determination by the Court of
- Appeals on remand. The judgment of the Court of Appeals is reversed, and
- the case is remanded for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.
- It is so ordered.
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
- ------------------------------------------------------------------------------
- 1
- Section 1 provides in pertinent part: "Every contract, combination in
- the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or
- commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to
- be illegal." 15 U. S. C. MDRV 1.
- Section 2 provides in pertinent part: "Every person who shall
- monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other
- person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among
- the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a
- felony." 15 U. S. C. MDRV 2.
-
- 2
- The monetary damages in this case were assessed entirely against COA,
- the District Court having ruled that the city was immunized by the Local
- Government Antitrust Act of 1984, 98 Stat. 2750, as amended, 15 U. S. C. 15
- 34-36, which exempts local governments from paying damages for violations
- of the federal antitrust laws. Although enacted in 1984, after the events
- at issue in this case, the Act specifically provides that it may be applied
- retroactively if "the defendant establishes and the court determines, in
- light of all the circumstances . . . that it would be inequitable not to
- apply this subsection to a pending case." 15 U. S. C. MDRV 35(b). The
- District Court determined that it would be, and the Court of Appeals
- refused to disturb that judgment. Respondent has not challenged that
- determination in this Court, and we express no view on the matter.
-
- 3
- S. C. Code MDRV 5-23-10 (1976) ("Building and zoning regulations
- authorized") provides that "[f]or the purpose of promoting health, safety,
- morals or the general welfare of the community, the legislative body of
- cities and incorporated towns may by ordinance regulate and restrict the
- height, number of stories and size of buildings and other structures."
- S. C. Code MDRV 5-23-20 (1976) ("Division of municipality into
- districts") provides that "[f]or any or all of such purposes the local
- legislative body may divide the municipality into districts of such number,
- shape and area as may be deemed best suited to carry out the purposes of
- this article. Within such districts it may regulate and restrict the
- erection, construction, reconstruction, alteration, repair or use of
- buildings, structures or land."
- S. C. Code MDRV 6-7-710 (1976) ("Grant of power for zoning") provides
- that "[f]or the purposes of guiding development in accordance with existing
- and future needs and in order to protect, promote and improve the public
- health, safety, morals, convenience, order, appearance, prosperity, and
- general welfare, the governing authorities of municipalities and counties
- may, in accordance with the conditions and procedures specified in this
- chapter, regulate the location, height, bulk, number of stories and size of
- buildings and other structures. . . . The regulations shall . . . be
- designed to lessen congestion in the streets; to secure safety from fire,
- panic, and other dangers, to promote the public health and the general
- welfare, to provide adequate light and air; to prevent the overcrowding of
- land; to avoid undue concentration of population; to protect scenic areas;
- to facilitate the adequate provision of transportation, water, sewage,
- schools, parks, and other public requirements."
-
- 4
- The dissent contends that, in order successfully to delegate its Parker
- immunity to a municipality, a State must expressly authorize the
- municipality to engage (1) in specifically "economic regulation," post, at
- 4, (2) of a specific industry, post at 7. These dual specificities are
- without support in our precedents, for the good reason that they defy
- rational implementation.
- If, by authority to engage in specifically "economic" regulation, the
- dissent means authority specifically to regulate competition, we squarely
- rejected that in Hallie, as discussed in text. Seemingly, however, the
- dissent means only that the State authorization must specify that sort of
- regulation whereunder "decisions about prices and output are not made by
- individual firms, but rather by a public body." Post, at 4. But why is
- not the restriction of billboards in a city a restriction on the "output"
- of the local billboard industry? It assuredly is -- and that is indeed the
- very gravamen of Omni's complaint. It seems to us that the dissent's
- concession that "it is often difficult to differentiate economic regulation
- from municipal regulation of health, safety, and welfare," post, at 9, is a
- gross understatement. Loose talk about a "regulated industry" may suffice
- for what the dissent calls "antitrust parlance," post, at 4, but it is not
- a definition upon which the criminal liability of public officials ought to
- depend.
- Under the dissent's second requirement for a valid delegation of Parker
- immunity -- that the authorization to regulate pertain to a specific
- industry -- the problem with the South Carolina statute is that it used the
- generic term "structures," instead of conferring its regulatory authority
- industry-by-industry (presumably "billboards," "movie houses," "mobile
- homes," "TV antennas," and every other conceivable object of zoning
- regulation that can be the subject of a relevant "market" for purposes of
- antitrust analysis). To describe this is to refute it. Our precedents not
- only fail to suggest but positively reject such an approach. "The
- municipality need not `be able to point to a specific, detailed legislative
- authorization' in order to assert a successful Parker defense to an
- antitrust suit." Hallie, 471 U. S., at 39 (quoting Lafayette, 435 U. S.,
- at 415).
-
- 5
- The dissent is confident that a jury composed of citizens of the
- vicinage will be able to tell the difference between "independent municipal
- action and action taken for the sole purpose of carrying out an
- anticompetitive agreement for the private party." Post, at 12. No doubt.
- But those are merely the polar extremes, which like the geographic poles
- will rarely be seen by jurors of the vicinage. Ordinarily the allegation
- will merely be (and the dissent says this is enough) that the municipal
- action was not prompted "exclusively by a concern for the general public
- interest," post, at 3 (emphasis added). Thus, the real question is whether
- a jury can tell the difference -- whether Solomon can tell the difference
- -- between
-